George Monbiot on landrights & planning
tliouk
office at tlio.demon.co.uk
Thu May 16 01:08:49 BST 2002
landrights & planning
Rich Man's Castle
Greens must not allow themselves to be used by the wealthy to shut
out low cost homes.
By George Monbiot. Published in the Guardian 7th May 2002
There is an inverse relationship between the attractiveness of an
English village and the attractiveness of the society which inhabits
it. Those ancient mossy churches, those half-timbered pubs, those
perfect rose gardens and sculpted yew trees are preserved not in
aspic but in vinegar.
The conservation of the "character" of the classic English village is
almost always double-edged. As landscape values become entangled with
social values, the "best kept villages" appear to be those best kept
away from the hoipolloi. As house prices have ensured that none but
the wealthy can afford to buy into the English dream, the wealthy in
many places are campaigning to ensure they stay that way.
They are not alone in opposing the construction of low-cost homes in
beautiful places. No company wants to build six pounds70,000 starter
homes if the same piece of land can be used to build one
pounds700,000 manor. "Exclusive" developments of luxury homes are
advertised everywhere, and exclusive is how both the builders and
many of the neighbours want them to remain.
This is not to say that people should not campaign to protect
beautiful places; simply that we must not conflate these campaigns
with attempts to protect some very ugly ideals. It is perfectly
possible, with sufficient government support, to build affordable
housing which is every bit as attractive as expensive housing can be.
But the economic cleansing in which both construction companies and
some residents conspire is exacerbating Britain's housing crisis.
As the builders concentrate on providing expensive homes in both
cities and the countryside, the rich have more choice than ever
before, just as the poor are discovering that there is nowhere to
turn. For the first time on record, the number of households in
England has overtaken the number of homes. In London alone,
officially homeless households are likely to double, to 110,000,
within ten years. Some 225,000 new homes are needed in England every
year, according to the Rowntree Foundation, but only 140,000 are
being built. The result is that prices in the United Kingdom last
month rose more steeply than they have ever done before: the cost of
a home increased in April by an average of pounds4000. By 2020, a
report published three weeks ago suggests, the average price of a
home could reach pounds300,000, or pounds600,000 in London.
The shortfall is blamed by the House Builders' Federation on greens
campaigning against new development in the countryside. In reality
its own members appear to be the principal culprits. Last week, the
Town and Country Planning Association revealed that construction
companies -- of which just a handful control much of the UK's
potential building land -- are sitting on their assets in order to
increase the value of the homes they sell. They have little incentive
to build now if they can ensure that prices continue to boom. They
have no incentive whatsoever to solve the underlying crisis by
building small cheap homes rather than large expensive ones.
But it is also true that many of those trying to preserve the
exclusivity of their communities have sheltered behind environmental
arguments, providing the housebuilders with the excuses they need to
sit tight. Some greenfield development will be necessary, and genuine
environmentalists must ensure that their campaigns cannot be used as
the drawbridge which keeps the poor out of the rich man's castle.
There are plenty of solid arguments for fighting sprawl, keeping new
development as compact as possible, regenerating run-down inner
cities and using brownfield land before building in the countryside.
Good urban design cuts crime, encourages social integration, permits
effective public transport and reduces inequality. Without it,
cities "dough-nut": the core dies, while the suburbs splurge. But
good urban design is the enemy of the big development companies.
Building on greenfield land is cheaper than clearing existing sites
and, if the land was bought at agricultural prices, far more
profitable.
But there are also some inherent contradictions which neither
environmentalists nor planners have properly addressed. One of these
is the paradox of regeneration. By rehabilitating a rundown area, in
order to improve the lives of the poor, regeneration often drives out
the very people it is supposed to help, by raising house prices. By
attracting companies to move into places which they have previously
shunned, it can boost overall economic activity while reducing the
amount of money circulating in the local economy, as small businesses
are displaced by multinationals expatriating their profits.
This is just one example of the clash between liveability and
inclusivity. House prices rise fastest and furthest in places with a
pleasant environment: by ensuring that communities stay compact and
well-served by public transport and public spaces, both councils and
campaigners can accidentally ensure that only the rich can afford to
live there.
What problems of this kind suggest is that housing provision simply
cannot be left to the market. Environmental quality and social
justice can be reconciled, but only if the government is prepared to
intervene. The first measure it must take is to use planning law to
hold down the cost of land. Development land reaches the value of the
most lucrative use to which it can be put. If land is zoned only or
largely for affordable housing, then its price falls accordingly.
This zoning would have to be accompanied by a time limit (after which
the land reverted to the community), to prevent developers from
sitting on it pending a change of policy.
Then the government needs both to raise revenue and to address the
extraordinary inequalities caused by house price inflation, by
levying a land value tax on development land and a capital gains tax
on main residences. The money this raised could then be used for
building the social housing Britain needs.
There is no room for second homes where others have none. The
privatisation of council housing should be reversed, as stock
transfer almost always leads to rising rents (ensuring that housing
benefit becomes an ever-growing subsidy for the banks). Car-free
developments, whose residents receive tax rebates in return for
relinquishing their cars, would allow compaction without sacrificing
environmental quality, making use of the vast amount of land that
planning law insists is allocated to parking. Perhaps, as this column
has suggested in the past, we need to consider moving the capital,
diverting some of London's economic activity to a place, such as
Liverpool, in which housing is abundant and new employment is scarce.
But none of this will happen until the greens join the housing
campaigners for a concerted battle against social exclusion.
Otherwise the government will have little incentive to listen to
anyone but the target voters of Middle England, seeking to acquire an
exclusive portion of the English dream, from which they can repel all
comers.
More information about the Diggers350
mailing list