Paul Mason: The end of capitalism has begun

mark mark mark at tlio.org.uk
Tue Jul 21 00:10:45 BST 2015


Comment: The end of capitalism has begun

By Paul Mason, The Guardian
17th July 2015
Ref:
http://www.theguardian.com/books/2015/jul/17/postcapitalism-end-of-capitalism-begun

The red flags and marching songs of Syriza during the Greek crisis, plus the
expectation that the banks would be nationalised, revived briefly a 20th-century
dream: the forced destruction of the market from above. For much of the 20th
century this was how the left conceived the first stage of an economy beyond
capitalism. The force would be applied by the working class, either at the
ballot box or on the barricades. The lever would be the state. The opportunity
would come through frequent episodes of economic collapse.

Instead over the past 25 years it has been the left’s project that has
collapsed. The market destroyed the plan; individualism replaced collectivism
and solidarity; the hugely expanded workforce of the world looks like a
“proletariat”, but no longer thinks or behaves as it once did.

If you lived through all this, and disliked capitalism, it was traumatic. But in
the process technology has created a new route out, which the remnants of the
old left – and all other forces influenced by it – have either to embrace or
die. Capitalism, it turns out, will not be abolished by forced-march techniques.
It will be abolished by creating something more dynamic that exists, at first,
almost unseen within the old system, but which will break through, reshaping the
economy around new values and behaviours. I call this postcapitalism.

As with the end of feudalism 500 years ago, capitalism’s replacement by
postcapitalism will be accelerated by external shocks and shaped by the
emergence of a new kind of human being. And it has started.

Postcapitalism is possible because of three major changes information technology
has brought about in the past 25 years. First, it has reduced the need for work,
blurred the edges between work and free time and loosened the relationship
between work and wages. The coming wave of automation, currently stalled because
our social infrastructure cannot bear the consequences, will hugely diminish the
amount of work needed – not just to subsist but to provide a decent life for
all.

Second, information is corroding the market’s ability to form prices correctly.
That is because markets are based on scarcity while information is abundant. The
system’s defence mechanism is to form monopolies – the giant tech companies – on
a scale not seen in the past 200 years, yet they cannot last. By building
business models and share valuations based on the capture and privatisation of
all socially produced information, such firms are constructing a fragile
corporate edifice at odds with the most basic need of humanity, which is to use
ideas freely.

Third, we’re seeing the spontaneous rise of collaborative production: goods,
services and organisations are appearing that no longer respond to the dictates
of the market and the managerial hierarchy. The biggest information product in
the world – Wikipedia – is made by volunteers for free, abolishing the
encyclopedia business and depriving the advertising industry of an estimated
$3bn a year in revenue.

Almost unnoticed, in the niches and hollows of the market system, whole swaths
of economic life are beginning to move to a different rhythm. Parallel
currencies, time banks, cooperatives and self-managed spaces have proliferated,
barely noticed by the economics profession, and often as a direct result of the
shattering of the old structures in the post-2008 crisis.

You only find this new economy if you look hard for it. In Greece, when a
grassroots NGO mapped the country’s food co-ops, alternative producers, parallel
currencies and local exchange systems they found more than 70 substantive
projects and hundreds of smaller initiatives ranging from squats to carpools to
free kindergartens. To mainstream economics such things seem barely to qualify
as economic activity – but that’s the point. They exist because they trade,
however haltingly and inefficiently, in the currency of postcapitalism: free
time, networked activity and free stuff. It seems a meagre and unofficial and
even dangerous thing from which to craft an entire alternative to a global
system, but so did money and credit in the age of Edward III.

New forms of ownership, new forms of lending, new legal contracts: a whole
business subculture has emerged over the past 10 years, which the media has
dubbed the “sharing economy”. Buzzwords such as the “commons” and
“peer-production” are thrown around, but few have bothered to ask what this
development means for capitalism itself.

I believe it offers an escape route – but only if these micro-level projects are
nurtured, promoted and protected by a fundamental change in what governments do.
And this must be driven by a change in our thinking – about technology,
ownership and work. So that, when we create the elements of the new system, we
can say to ourselves, and to others: “This is no longer simply my survival
mechanism, my bolt hole from the neoliberal world; this is a new way of living
in the process of formation.”

The 2008 crash wiped 13% off global production and 20% off global trade. Global
growth became negative – on a scale where anything below +3% is counted as a
recession. It produced, in the west, a depression phase longer than in 1929-33,
and even now, amid a pallid recovery, has left mainstream economists terrified
about the prospect of long-term stagnation. The aftershocks in Europe are
tearing the continent apart.

The solutions have been austerity plus monetary excess. But they are not
working. In the worst hit countries, the pension system has been destroyed, the
retirement age is being hiked to 70, and education is being privatised so that
graduates now face a lifetime of high debt. Services are being dismantled and
infrastructure projects put on hold.

Even now many people fail to grasp the true meaning of the word “austerity”.
Austerity is not eight years of spending cuts, as in the UK, or even the social
catastrophe inflicted on Greece. It means driving the wages, social wages and
living standards in the west down for decades until they meet those of the
middle class in China and India on the way up.

Meanwhile in the absence of any alternative model, the conditions for another
crisis are being assembled. Real wages have fallen or remained stagnant in
Japan, the southern Eurozone, the US and UK. The shadow banking system has been
reassembled, and is now bigger than it was in 2008. New rules demanding banks
hold more reserves have been watered down or delayed. Meanwhile, flushed with
free money, the 1% has got richer.

Neoliberalism, then, has morphed into a system programmed to inflict recurrent
catastrophic failures. Worse than that, it has broken the 200-year pattern of
industrial capitalism wherein an economic crisis spurs new forms of
technological innovation that benefit everybody.

That is because neoliberalism was the first economic model in 200 years the
upswing of which was premised on the suppression of wages and smashing the
social power and resilience of the working class. If we review the take-off
periods studied by long-cycle theorists – the 1850s in Europe, the 1900s and
1950s across the globe – it was the strength of organised labour that forced
entrepreneurs and corporations to stop trying to revive outdated business models
through wage cuts, and to innovate their way to a new form of capitalism.

The result is that, in each upswing, we find a synthesis of automation, higher
wages and higher value consumption. Today there is no pressure from the
workforce, and the technology at the centre of this innovation wave does not
demand the creation of higher-consumer spending, or the re‑employment of the old
workforce in new jobs. Information is a machine for grinding the price of things
lower and slashing the work time needed to support life on the planet.

As a result, large parts of the business class have become neo-luddites. Faced
with the possibility of creating gene-sequencing labs, they instead start coffee
shops, nail bars and contract cleaning firms: the banking system, the planning
system and late neoliberal culture reward above all the creator of low-value,
long-hours jobs.

Innovation is happening but it has not, so far, triggered the fifth long upswing
for capitalism that long-cycle theory would expect. The reasons lie in the
specific nature of information technology.

We’re surrounded not just by intelligent machines but by a new layer of reality
centred on information. Consider an airliner: a computer flies it; it has been
designed, stress-tested and “virtually manufactured” millions of times; it is
firing back real-time information to its manufacturers. On board are people
squinting at screens connected, in some lucky countries, to the internet.

Seen from the ground it is the same white metal bird as in the James Bond era.
But it is now both an intelligent machine and a node on a network. It has an
information content and is adding “information value” as well as physical value
to the world. On a packed business flight, when everyone’s peering at Excel or
Powerpoint, the passenger cabin is best understood as an information factory.

But what is all this information worth? You won’t find an answer in the
accounts: intellectual property is valued in modern accounting standards by
guesswork. A study for the SAS Institute in 2013 found that, in order to put a
value on data, neither the cost of gathering it, nor the market value or the
future income from it could be adequately calculated. Only through a form of
accounting that included non-economic benefits, and risks, could companies
actually explain to their shareholders what their data was really worth.
Something is broken in the logic we use to value the most important thing in the
modern world.

The great technological advance of the early 21st century consists not only of
new objects and processes, but of old ones made intelligent. The knowledge
content of products is becoming more valuable than the physical things that are
used to produce them. But it is a value measured as usefulness, not exchange or
asset value. In the 1990s economists and technologists began to have the same
thought at once: that this new role for information was creating a new, “third”
kind of capitalism – as different from industrial capitalism as industrial
capitalism was to the merchant and slave capitalism of the 17th and 18th
centuries. But they have struggled to describe the dynamics of the new
“cognitive” capitalism. And for a reason. Its dynamics are profoundly
non-capitalist.

During and right after the second world war, economists viewed information
simply as a “public good”. The US government even decreed that no profit should
be made out of patents, only from the production process itself. Then we began
to understand intellectual property. In 1962, Kenneth Arrow, the guru of
mainstream economics, said that in a free market economy the purpose of
inventing things is to create intellectual property rights. He noted: “precisely
to the extent that it is successful there is an underutilisation of
information.”

You can observe the truth of this in every e-business model ever constructed:
monopolise and protect data, capture the free social data generated by user
interaction, push commercial forces into areas of data production that were
non-commercial before, mine the existing data for predictive value – always and
everywhere ensuring nobody but the corporation can utilise the results.

If we restate Arrow’s principle in reverse, its revolutionary implications are
obvious: if a free market economy plus intellectual property leads to the
“underutilisation of information”, then an economy based on the full utilisation
of information cannot tolerate the free market or absolute intellectual property
rights. The business models of all our modern digital giants are designed to
prevent the abundance of information.

Yet information is abundant. Information goods are freely replicable. Once a
thing is made, it can be copied/pasted infinitely. A music track or the giant
database you use to build an airliner has a production cost; but its cost of
reproduction falls towards zero. Therefore, if the normal price mechanism of
capitalism prevails over time, its price will fall towards zero, too.

For the past 25 years economics has been wrestling with this problem: all
mainstream economics proceeds from a condition of scarcity, yet the most dynamic
force in our modern world is abundant and, as hippy genius Stewart Brand once
put it, “wants to be free”.

There is, alongside the world of monopolised information and surveillance
created by corporations and governments, a different dynamic growing up around
information: information as a social good, free at the point of use, incapable
of being owned or exploited or priced. I’ve surveyed the attempts by economists
and business gurus to build a framework to understand the dynamics of an economy
based on abundant, socially-held information. But it was actually imagined by
one 19th-century economist in the era of the telegraph and the steam engine. His
name? Karl Marx.

The scene is Kentish Town, London, February 1858, sometime around 4am. Marx is a
wanted man in Germany and is hard at work scribbling thought-experiments and
notes-to-self. When they finally get to see what Marx is writing on this night,
the left intellectuals of the 1960s will admit that it “challenges every serious
interpretation of Marx yet conceived”. It is called “The Fragment on Machines”.

In the “Fragment” Marx imagines an economy in which the main role of machines is
to produce, and the main role of people is to supervise them. He was clear that,
in such an economy, the main productive force would be information. The
productive power of such machines as the automated cotton-spinning machine, the
telegraph and the steam locomotive did not depend on the amount of labour it
took to produce them but on the state of social knowledge. Organisation and
knowledge, in other words, made a bigger contribution to productive power than
the work of making and running the machines.

Given what Marxism was to become – a theory of exploitation based on the theft
of labour time - this is a revolutionary statement. It suggests that, once
knowledge becomes a productive force in its own right, outweighing the actual
labour spent creating a machine, the big question becomes not one of “wages
versus profits” but who controls what Marx called the “power of knowledge”.

In an economy where machines do most of the work, the nature of the knowledge
locked inside the machines must, he writes, be “social”. In a final late-night
thought experiment Marx imagined the end point of this trajectory: the creation
of an “ideal machine”, which lasts forever and costs nothing. A machine that
could be built for nothing would, he said, add no value at all to the production
process and rapidly, over several accounting periods, reduce the price, profit
and labour costs of everything else it touched.

Once you understand that information is physical, and that software is a
machine, and that storage, bandwidth and processing power are collapsing in
price at exponential rates, the value of Marx’s thinking becomes clear. We are
surrounded by machines that cost nothing and could, if we wanted them to, last
forever.

In these musings, not published until the mid-20th century, Marx imagined
information coming to be stored and shared in something called a “general
intellect” – which was the mind of everybody on Earth connected by social
knowledge, in which every upgrade benefits everybody. In short, he had imagined
something close to the information economy in which we live. And, he wrote, its
existence would “blow capitalism sky high”.With the terrain changed, the old
path beyond capitalism imagined by the left of the 20th century is lost.

But a different path has opened up. Collaborative production, using network
technology to produce goods and services that only work when they are free, or
shared, defines the route beyond the market system. It will need the state to
create the framework – just as it created the framework for factory labour,
sound currencies and free trade in the early 19th century. The postcapitalist
sector is likely to coexist with the market sector for decades, but major change
is happening.

Networks restore “granularity” to the postcapitalist project. That is, they can
be the basis of a non-market system that replicates itself, which does not need
to be created afresh every morning on the computer screen of a commissar.

The transition will involve the state, the market and collaborative production
beyond the market. But to make it happen, the entire project of the left, from
protest groups to the mainstream social democratic and liberal parties, will
have to be reconfigured. In fact, once people understand the logic of the
postcapitalist transition, such ideas will no longer be the property of the left
– but of a much wider movement, for which we will need new labels.

Who can make this happen? In the old left project it was the industrial working
class. More than 200 years ago, the radical journalist John Thelwall warned the
men who built the English factories that they had created a new and dangerous
form of democracy: “Every large workshop and manufactory is a sort of political
society, which no act of parliament can silence, and no magistrate disperse.”

Today the whole of society is a factory. We all participate in the creation and
recreation of the brands, norms and institutions that surround us. At the same
time the communication grids vital for everyday work and profit are buzzing with
shared knowledge and discontent. Today it is the network – like the workshop 200
years ago – that they “cannot silence or disperse”.

True, states can shut down Facebook, Twitter, even the entire internet and
mobile network in times of crisis, paralysing the economy in the process. And
they can store and monitor every kilobyte of information we produce. But they
cannot reimpose the hierarchical, propaganda-driven and ignorant society of 50
years ago, except – as in China, North Korea or Iran – by opting out of key
parts of modern life. It would be, as sociologist Manuel Castells put it, like
trying to de-electrify a country.

By creating millions of networked people, financially exploited but with the
whole of human intelligence one thumb-swipe away, info-capitalism has created a
new agent of change in history: the educated and connected human being.

This will be more than just an economic transition. There are, of course, the
parallel and urgent tasks of decarbonising the world and dealing with
demographic and fiscal timebombs. But I’m concentrating on the economic
transition triggered by information because, up to now, it has been sidelined.
Peer-to-peer has become pigeonholed as a niche obsession for visionaries, while
the “big boys” of leftwing economics get on with critiquing austerity.

In fact, on the ground in places such as Greece, resistance to austerity and the
creation of “networks you can’t default on” – as one activist put it to me – go
hand in hand. Above all, postcapitalism as a concept is about new forms of human
behaviour that conventional economics would hardly recognise as relevant.

So how do we visualise the transition ahead? The only coherent parallel we have
is the replacement of feudalism by capitalism – and thanks to the work of
epidemiologists, geneticists and data analysts, we know a lot more about that
transition than we did 50 years ago when it was “owned” by social science. The
first thing we have to recognise is: different modes of production are
structured around different things. Feudalism was an economic system structured
by customs and laws about “obligation”. Capitalism was structured by something
purely economic: the market. We can predict, from this, that postcapitalism –
whose precondition is abundance – will not simply be a modified form of a
complex market society. But we can only begin to grasp at a positive vision of
what it will be like.

I don’t mean this as a way to avoid the question: the general economic
parameters of a postcapitalist society by, for example, the year 2075, can be
outlined. But if such a society is structured around human liberation, not
economics, unpredictable things will begin to shape it.

For example, the most obvious thing to Shakespeare, writing in 1600, was that
the market had called forth new kinds of behaviour and morality. By analogy, the
most obvious “economic” thing to the Shakespeare of 2075 will be the total
upheaval in gender relationships, or sexuality, or health. Perhaps there will
not even be any playwrights: perhaps the very nature of the media we use to tell
stories will change – just as it changed in Elizabethan London when the first
public theatres were built.

Think of the difference between, say, Horatio in Hamlet and a character such as
Daniel Doyce in Dickens’s Little Dorrit. Both carry around with them a
characteristic obsession of their age – Horatio is obsessed with humanist
philosophy; Doyce is obsessed with patenting his invention. There can be no
character like Doyce in Shakespeare; he would, at best, get a bit part as a
working-class comic figure. Yet, by the time Dickens described Doyce, most of
his readers knew somebody like him. Just as Shakespeare could not have imagined
Doyce, so we too cannot imagine the kind of human beings society will produce
once economics is no longer central to life. But we can see their prefigurative
forms in the lives of young people all over the world breaking down 20th-century
barriers around sexuality, work, creativity and the self.

The feudal model of agriculture collided, first, with environmental limits and
then with a massive external shock – the Black Death. After that, there was a
demographic shock: too few workers for the land, which raised their wages and
made the old feudal obligation system impossible to enforce. The labour shortage
also forced technological innovation. The new technologies that underpinned the
rise of merchant capitalism were the ones that stimulated commerce (printing and
accountancy), the creation of tradeable wealth (mining, the compass and fast
ships) and productivity (mathematics and the scientific method).

Present throughout the whole process was something that looks incidental to the
old system – money and credit – but which was actually destined to become the
basis of the new system. In feudalism, many laws and customs were actually
shaped around ignoring money; credit was, in high feudalism, seen as sinful. So
when money and credit burst through the boundaries to create a market system, it
felt like a revolution. Then, what gave the new system its energy was the
discovery of a virtually unlimited source of free wealth in the Americas.

A combination of all these factors took a set of people who had been
marginalised under feudalism – humanists, scientists, craftsmen, lawyers,
radical preachers and bohemian playwrights such as Shakespeare – and put them at
the head of a social transformation. At key moments, though tentatively at
first, the state switched from hindering the change to promoting it.

Today, the thing that is corroding capitalism, barely rationalised by mainstream
economics, is information. Most laws concerning information define the right of
corporations to hoard it and the right of states to access it, irrespective of
the human rights of citizens. The equivalent of the printing press and the
scientific method is information technology and its spillover into all other
technologies, from genetics to healthcare to agriculture to the movies, where it
is quickly reducing costs.

The modern equivalent of the long stagnation of late feudalism is the stalled
take-off of the third industrial revolution, where instead of rapidly automating
work out of existence, we are reduced to creating what David Graeber calls
“bullshit jobs” on low pay. And many economies are stagnating.

The equivalent of the new source of free wealth? It’s not exactly wealth: it’s
the “externalities” – the free stuff and wellbeing generated by networked
interaction. It is the rise of non-market production, of unownable information,
of peer networks and unmanaged enterprises. The internet, French economist Yann
Moulier-Boutang says, is “both the ship and the ocean” when it comes to the
modern equivalent of the discovery of the new world. In fact, it is the ship,
the compass, the ocean and the gold.

The modern day external shocks are clear: energy depletion, climate change,
ageing populations and migration. They are altering the dynamics of capitalism
and making it unworkable in the long term. They have not yet had the same impact
as the Black Death – but as we saw in New Orleans in 2005, it does not take the
bubonic plague to destroy social order and functional infrastructure in a
financially complex and impoverished society.

Once you understand the transition in this way, the need is not for a
supercomputed Five Year Plan – but a project, the aim of which should be to
expand those technologies, business models and behaviours that dissolve market
forces, socialise knowledge, eradicate the need for work and push the economy
towards abundance. I call it Project Zero – because its aims are a
zero-carbon-energy system; the production of machines, products and services
with zero marginal costs; and the reduction of necessary work time as close as
possible to zero.

Most 20th-century leftists believed that they did not have the luxury of a
managed transition: it was an article of faith for them that nothing of the
coming system could exist within the old one – though the working class always
attempted to create an alternative life within and “despite” capitalism. As a
result, once the possibility of a Soviet-style transition disappeared, the
modern left became preoccupied simply with opposing things: the privatisation of
healthcare, anti-union laws, fracking – the list goes on.

If I am right, the logical focus for supporters of postcapitalism is to build
alternatives within the system; to use governmental power in a radical and
disruptive way; and to direct all actions towards the transition – not the
defence of random elements of the old system. We have to learn what’s urgent,
and what’s important, and that sometimes they do not coincide.

The power of imagination will become critical. In an information society, no
thought, debate or dream is wasted – whether conceived in a tent camp, prison
cell or the table football space of a startup company.

As with virtual manufacturing, in the transition to postcapitalism the work done
at the design stage can reduce mistakes in the implementation stage. And the
design of the postcapitalist world, as with software, can be modular. Different
people can work on it in different places, at different speeds, with relative
autonomy from each other. If I could summon one thing into existence for free it
would be a global institution that modelled capitalism correctly: an open source
model of the whole economy; official, grey and black. Every experiment run
through it would enrich it; it would be open source and with as many datapoints
as the most complex climate models.

The main contradiction today is between the possibility of free, abundant goods
and information; and a system of monopolies, banks and governments trying to
keep things private, scarce and commercial. Everything comes down to the
struggle between the network and the hierarchy: between old forms of society
moulded around capitalism and new forms of society that prefigure what comes
next.

Is it utopian to believe we’re on the verge of an evolution beyond capitalism?
We live in a world in which gay men and women can marry, and in which
contraception has, within the space of 50 years, made the average working-class
woman freer than the craziest libertine of the Bloomsbury era. Why do we, then,
find it so hard to imagine economic freedom?

It is the elites – cut off in their dark-limo world – whose project looks as
forlorn as that of the millennial sects of the 19th century. The democracy of
riot squads, corrupt politicians, magnate-controlled newspapers and the
surveillance state looks as phoney and fragile as East Germany did 30 years ago.

All readings of human history have to allow for the possibility of a negative
outcome. It haunts us in the zombie movie, the disaster movie, in the
post-apocalytic wasteland of films such as The Road or Elysium. But why should
we not form a picture of the ideal life, built out of abundant information,
non-hierarchical work and the dissociation of work from wages?

Millions of people are beginning to realise they have been sold a dream at odds
with what reality can deliver. Their response is anger – and retreat towards
national forms of capitalism that can only tear the world apart. Watching these
emerge, from the pro-Grexit left factions in Syriza to the Front National and
the isolationism of the American right has been like watching the nightmares we
had during the Lehman Brothers crisis come true.

We need more than just a bunch of utopian dreams and small-scale horizontal
projects. We need a project based on reason, evidence and testable designs, that
cuts with the grain of history and is sustainable by the planet. And we need to
get on with it.

Postcapitalism is published by Allen Lane on 30 July.



More information about the Diggers350 mailing list